Herbert
Simon's idea of satisfying solves that problem. A satisfier,
searching for a mate, would have an aspiration level. Once
this aspiration is met, as long as it is not too high, he
will find the partner and the problem is solved. But satisfying
is also a purely cognitive mechanism. After you make your
choice you might see someone come around the corner who
looks better, and there's nothing to prevent you from dropping
your wife or your husband and going off with the next one.
Here we see one function of emotions. Love, whether it be
romantic love or love for our children, helps most of us
to create a commitment necessary to make us stay with and
take care of our spouses and families. Emotions can perform
functions that are similar to those that cognitive building
blocks of heuristics perform. Disgust, for example, keeps
you from eating lots of things and makes food choice much
simpler, and other emotions do similar things. Still, we
have very little understanding of how decision theory links
with the theory of emotion, and how we develop a good vocabulary
of building blocks necessary for making decisions. This
is one direction in which it is important to investigate
in the future.
Another simple example of how heuristics are useful can
be seen in the following thought experiment: Assume you
want to study how players catch balls that come in from
a high angle like in baseball, cricket, or soccer
because you want to build a robot that can catch
them. The traditional approach, which is much like optimization
under constraints, would be to try to give your robot the
complete representation of its environment and the most
expensive computation machinery you can afford. You might
feed your robot a family of parabolas because thrown balls
have parabolic trajectories, with the idea that the robot
needs to find the right parabola in order to catch the ball.
Or you feed him measurement instruments that can measure
the initial distance, the initial velocity, and the initial
angle the ball was thrown or kicked. You're still not done
because in the real world balls are not flying parabolas,
so you need instruments that can measure the direction and
the speed of the wind at each point of the ball's flight
to calculate its final trajectory and its spin. It's a very
hard problem, but this is one way to look at it.
A very different way to approach this is to ask if there
is a heuristic that a player could actually use to solve
this problem without making any of these calculations, or
only very few. Experimental studies have shown that actual
players use a quite simple heuristic that I call the gaze
heuristic. When a ball comes in high, a player starts running
and fixates his eyes on the ball. The heuristic is that
you adjust your running speed so that the angle of the gaze,
the angle between the eye and the ball, remains constant.
If you make the angle constant the ball will come down to
you and it will catch you, or at least it will hit you.
This heuristic only pays attention to one variable, the
angle of gaze, and can ignore all the other causal, relevant
variables and achieve the same goal much faster, more frugally,
and with less chances for error.
This illustrates that we can do the science of calculation
by looking always at what the mind does the heuristics
and the structures of environments and how minds
change the structures of environments. In this case the
relationship between the ball and one's self is turned into
a simple linear relationship on which the player acts. This
is an example of a smart heuristic, which is part of the
adaptive tool box that has evolved in humans. Many of these
heuristics are also present in animals. For instance, a
recent study showed that when dogs catch frisbees they use
the same gaze heuristic.
Heuristics are also useful in very important practical ways
relating to economics. To illustrate I'll give you a short
story about our research on a heuristic concerning the stock
market. One very smart and simple heuristic is called the
recognition heuristic. Here is a demonstration: Which of
the following two cities has more inhabitants Hanover
or Bielefeld? I pick these two German cities assuming that
you don't know very much about Germany. Most people will
think it's Hanover because they have never heard of Bielefeld,
and they're right. However, if I pose the same question
to Germans, they are insecure and don't know which to choose.
They've heard of both of them and try to recall information.
The same thing can be done in reverse. We have done studies
with Daniel Gray Goldstein in which we ask Americans which
city has more inhabitants San Diego or San Antonio?
About two-thirds of my former undergraduates at the University
of Chicago got the right answer: San Diego. Then we asked
German students who know much less about San Diego
and many of whom had never even heard of San Antonio
the same question. What proportion of the German students
do you think got the answer right? In our study, a hundred
percent. They hadn't heard of San Antonio, so they picked
San Diego. This is an interesting case of a smart heuristic,
where people with less knowledge can do better than people
with more. The reason this works is because in the real
world there is a correlation between name recognition and
things like populations. You have heard of a city because
there is something happening there. It's not an indicator
of certainty, but it's a good stimulus.
In my group at the Max Planck Institute for Human Development
I work alongside a spectrum of researchers, several of whom
are economists, who work on the same topics but ask a different
kind of question. They say, "That's all fine that you can
demonstrate that you can get away with less knowledge, but
can the recognition heuristic make money?" In order to answer
this question we did a large study with the American and
German stock markets, involving both lay people and students
of business and finance in both countries. We went to downtown
Chicago and interviewed several hundred pedestrians. We
gave them a list of stocks and asked them one question:
Have you ever heard of this stock? Yes or no? Then we took
the ten percent of the stocks that had the highest recognition,
which were all stocks in the Standard & Poor's Index, put
them in the portfolio and let them go for half a year. As
a control, we did the same thing with the same American
pedestrians with German stocks. In this case they had heard
of very few of them. As a third control we had German pedestrians
in downtown Munich perform the same recognition ratings
with German and American stocks. The question in this experiment
is not how much money the portfolio makes, but whether it
makes more money than some standards, of which we had four.
One consisted of randomly picked stocks, which is a tough
standard. A second one contained the least-recognized stocks,
which is according to the theory an important standard,
and shouldn't do as well. In the third we had blue chip
funds, like Fidelity II. And in the last we had the market
the Dow and its German equivalent. We let this run
for six months, and after six months the portfolios containing
the highest recognized stocks by ordinary people outperformed
the randomly picked stocks, the low recognition stocks,
and in six out of eight cases the market and the mutual
funds.
Although this was an interesting study, one should of course
be cautious, because unlike in other experimental and real
world studies, we have a variable and very random environment.
But what this study at least showed is that the recognition
of ordinary citizens can actually beat out the performance
of the market and other important criteria. The empirical
evidence, of course the background is consumer
behavior. In many situations when people in a supermarket
choose between products they go with the item with name
recognition. Advertising by companies like Benetton exploits
the use of the recognition heuristic. They give us no information
about the product, but only increase name recognition. It
has been a very successful strategy for the firm.
Of course the reaction to this study, which is published
in our book Simple Heuristics that Make Us Work,
has split the experts in two camps. One group said this
can't be true, that it's all wrong, or it could never be
replicated. Among them were financial advisers, who certainly
didn't like the results. Another group of people said, "This
is no surprise. I knew it all along. The stock market's
all rumor, recognition, and psychology." Meanwhile, we have
replicated these studies several times and found the same
advantage of recognition in bull and bear market
and also found that recognition among those who knew
less did best of all in our studies.
I would like to share these ideas with many others, to use
psychological research, and to use what we know about how
to facilitate people's understanding of uncertainties to
help to promote this old dream about getting an educated
citizenship that can deal with uncertainties, rather than
denying their existence. Understanding the mind as a tool
that tries to live in an uncertain world is an important
challenge.